DOI: https://doi.org/10.20529/IJME.2018.089
“Sustaining for-profit emergency healthcare services in low resource areas” by Jain et al (1) is an excellent reply to the Bawaskars (2). Clearly, the state must prevent both patients from going bankrupt and practitioners from running into negative balances.
However, two points made in the commentary are contestable:
Is there any evidence to support this statement? Probably the income of private doctors in rural areas varies with the number and paying capacity of patients. In Eastern Europe (eg, Romania (3)) and in drought-hit areas—if the number of patients remained constant—the real income of doctors would fall with that of their patients. Any increase in income would be proportionate to that of the economic milieu or the number of patients seen.
Here, the rapid expansion of private services has been mostly in urban areas. Data is unlikely to show much private expansion in the rural areas. The push to go for higher end treatment is market driven, related to liberalisation rather than to an actual decrease in public facility performance or decrease in performance per unit population.
In 2016, there were 209,010 government beds in rural areas compared to 111,872 in 2005 (90% increase). In the same period government beds in the urban areas saw only a 45% increase (425,869 in 2016 against 292,813 in 2005) (4, 5). So, there have always been more government beds in urban areas than in rural areas even though 69% population is in rural areas. But only 3% of the doctor population lives in rural areas (4). Since one third of government beds are in rural areas, and the existence of one third of government beds in rural areas presumably draws 30% government doctors to rural work, we can assume that 7% of doctors are government employees working in urban areas. It seems that the overwhelming majority of all doctors is in the urban private sector.